What is Communist Anarchism? Ch27!

in #communism4 years ago

This is the 29th installment of Alexander Berkman's book, What is Communist Anarchism, it can be found in the Anarchists' Library.

What has really stuck with me throughout this book is that very little has changed since these words were written.
Largely life then was just like now.
Same worries about rent.
Same worries about taxes.

You'd think we could improve on that during the most technologically advanced century ever, but nope,...

image.png

Chapter 27: Organization of Labor for the Social Revolution

Proper preparation, as suggested in the preceding pages, will greatly lighten the task of the social revolution and assure its healthy development and functioning.

Now, what will be the main functions of the revolution?

Every country has its specific conditions, its own psychology, habits, and traditions, and the process of revolution will naturally reflect the peculiarities of every land and its people.
But fundamentally all countries are alike in their social (rather anti-social) character: whatever the political forms or economic conditions, they are all built on invasive authority, on monopoly, on the exploitation of labor.
The main task of the social revolution is therefore essentially the same everywhere: the abolition of government and of economic inequality, and the socialization of the means of production and distribution.

Production, distribution, and communication are the basic sources of existence; upon them rests the power of coercive authority and capital.
Deprived of that power, governors and rulers become just ordinary men, like you and me, common citizens among millions of others.
To accomplish that is consequently the primal and most vital function of the social revolution.

We know that revolution begins with street disturbances and outbreaks: it is the initial phase which involves force and violence.
But that is merely the spectacular prologue of the real revolution.
The age long misery and indignity suffered by the masses burst into disorder and tumult, the humiliation and injustice meekly borne for decades find vent in acts of fury and destruction.
That is inevitable, and it is solely the master class which is responsible for this preliminary character of revolution.
For it is even more true socially than individually that “whoever sows the wind will reap the whirlwind”: the greater the oppression and wretchedness to which the masses had been made to submit, the fiercer will rage the social storm.
All history proves it, but the lords of life have never harkened to its warning voice.

This phase of the revolution is of short duration.
It is usually followed by the more conscious, yet still spontaneous, destruction of the citadels of authority, the visible symbols of organized violence and brutality: jails, police stations, and other government buildings are attacked, the prisoners liberated, legal documents destroyed.
It is the manifestation of instinctive popular justice.
Thus one of the first gestures of the French Revolution was the demolition of the Bastille.
Similarly in Russia prisons were stormed and the prisoners released at the very outset of the Revolution.[19]
The wholesome intuition of the people justly sees in prisoners social unfortunates, victims of conditions, and sympathizes with them as such.
The masses regard the courts and their records as instruments of class injustice, and these are destroyed at the beginning of the revolution, and quite properly so.

But this stage passes quickly: the people’s ire is soon spent.
Simultaneously the revolution begins its constructive work.

“Do you really think that reconstruction could start so soon?” you ask.

My friend, it must begin immediately.
In fact, the more enlightened the masses have become, the clearer the workers realize their aims, and the better they are prepared to carry them out, the less destructive the revolution will be, and the quicker and more effectively will begin the work of reconstruction.

“Are you not too hopeful?”

No, I don’t think so.
I am convinced that the social revolution will not “just happen.”
It will have to be prepared, organized.
Yes, indeed, organized — just as a strike is organized.
In truth, it will be a strike, the strike of the united workers of an entire country — a general strike.

Let us pause and consider this.

How do you imagine a revolution could be fought in these days of armored tanks, poison gas, and military planes?
Do you believe that the unarmed masses and their barricades could withstand high-power artillery and bombs thrown upon them from flying machines?
Could labor fight the military forces of government and capital?

It’s ridiculous on the face of it, isn’t it?
And no less ridiculous is the suggestion that the workers should form their own regiments, “shock troops,” or a “red front,” as the Communist parties advise you to do.
Will such proletarian bodies ever be able to stand up against the trained armies of the government and the private troops of capital?
Will they have the least chance?

Such a proposition needs only to be stated to be seen in all its impossible folly.
It would simply mean sending thousands of workers to certain death.

It is time to have done with this obsolete idea of revolution.
Nowadays government and capital are too well organized in a military way for the workers ever to be able to cope with them.
It would be criminal to attempt it, insanity even to think of it.

The strength of labor is not on the field of battle.
It is in the shop, in the mine and factory.
There lies its power that no army in the world can defeat, no human agency conquer.

In other words, the social revolution can take place only by means of the General Strike.
The General Strike, rightly understood and thoroughly carried out, is the social revolution.
Of this the British Government became aware much quicker than the workers when the General Strike was declared in England in May, 1926.
“It means revolution,” the Government said, in effect, to the strike leaders.
With all their armies and navies the authorities were powerless in the face of the situation.
You can shoot people to death but you can’t shoot them to work.
The labor leaders themselves were frightened at the thought that the General Strike actually implied revolution.

British capital and government won the strike — not by the strength of arms, but because of the lack of intelligence and courage on the part of the labor leaders and because the English workers were not prepared for the consequences of the General Strike.
As a matter of fact, the idea was quite new to them.
They had never before been interested in it, never studied its significance and potentialities.
It is safe to say that a similar situation in France would have developed quite differently, because in that country the toilers have for years been familiar with the General Strike as a revolutionary proletarian weapon.

It is most important that we realize that the General Strike is the only possibility of social revolution.
In the past the General Strike has been propagated in various countries without sufficient emphasis that its real meaning is revolution, that it is the only practical way to it.
It is time for us to learn this, and when we do so the social revolution will cease to be a vague, unknown quantity.
It will become an actuality, a definite method and aim, a program whose first step is the taking over of the industries by organized labor.

I understand now why you said that the social revolution means construction rather than destruction,” your friend remarks.

I am glad you do.
And if you have followed me so far, you will agree that the matter of taking over the industries is not something that can be left to chance, nor can it be carried out in a haphazard manner.
It can be accomplished only in a well-planned, systematic, and organized way.
You alone can’t do it, nor I, nor any other man, be he worker, Ford, or the Pope of Rome.
There is no man nor any body of men that can manage it except the workers themselves, for it takes the workers to operate the industries.
But even the workers can’t do it unless they are organized and organized just for such an undertaking.

“But I thought you were an Anarchist,” interrupts your friend.

I am.

“I’ve heard that Anarchists don’t believe in organization.”

I imagine you have, but that’s an old argument.
Any one who tells you that Anarchists don’t believe in organization is talking nonsense.
Organization is everything, and everything is organization.
The whole of life is organization, conscious or unconscious.
Every nation, every family, why, even every individual is an organization or organism.
Every part of every living thing is organized in such a manner that the whole works in harmony.
Otherwise the different organs could not function properly and life could not exist.

But there is organization and organization.
Capitalist society is so badly organized that its various members suffer: just as when you have pain in some part of you, your whole body aches and you are ill.

There is organization that is painful because it is ill, and organization that is joyous because it means health and strength.
An organization is ill or evil when it neglects or suppresses any of its organs or members.
In the healthy organism all parts are equally valuable and none is discriminated against.
The organization built on compulsion, which coerces and forces, is bad and unhealthy.
The libertarian organization, formed voluntarily and in which every member is free and equal, is a sound body and can work well.
Such an organization is a free union of equal parts.
It is the kind of organization the Anarchists believe in.

Such must be the organization of the workers if labor is to have a healthy body, one that can operate effectively.

It means, first of all, that not a single member of the organization or union may with impunity be discriminated against, suppressed or ignored.
To do so would be the same as to ignore an aching tooth: you would be sick all over.

In other words, the labor union must be built on the principle of the equal liberty of all its members.

Only when each is a free and independent unit, coöperating with the others from his own choice because of mutual interests, can the whole work successfully and become powerful.

This equality means that it makes no difference what or who the particular worker is: whether he is skilled or unskilled, whether he is mason, carpenter, engineer or day laborer, whether he earn much or little.
The interests of all are the same; all belong together, and only by standing together can they accomplish their purpose.

It means that the workers in the factory, mill, or mine must be organized as one body; for it is not a question of what particular jobs they hold, what craft or trade they follow, but what their interests are.
And their interests are identical, as against the employer and the system of exploitation.

Consider yourself how foolish and inefficient is the present form of labor organization in which one trade or craft may be on strike while the other branches of the same industry continue at work.
Is it not ridiculous that when the street car workers of New York, for instance, quit work, the employees of the subway, the cab and omnibus drivers remain on the job?
The main purpose of a strike is to bring about a situation that will compel the employer to give in to the demands of labor.
Such a situation can be created only by a complete tie-up of the industry in question, so that a partial strike is merely a waste of labor’s time and energy, not to speak of the harmful moral effect of the inevitable defeat.

Think over the strikes in which you yourself have taken part and of others you know of.
Did your union ever win a fight unless it was able to compel the employer to give in?
But when was it able to do so?
Only when the boss knew that the workers meant business, that there was no dissent among them, that there was no hesitation and dallying, that they were determined to win, at whatever cost.
But particularly when the employer felt himself at the mercy of the union, when he could not operate his factory or mine in the face of the workers’ resolute stand, when he could not get scabs or strikebreakers, and when he saw that his interests would suffer more by defying his employees than by granting their demands.

It is clear, then, that you can compel compliance only when you are determined, when your union is strong, when you are well organized, when you are united in such a manner that the boss cannot run his factory against your will.
But the employer is usually some big manufacturer or a company that has mills or mines in various places.
Suppose it is a coal combine.
If it cannot operate its mines in Pennsylvania because of a strike, it will try to make good its losses by continuing mining in Virginia or Colorado and increasing production there.
Now, if the miners in those States keep on working while you in Pennsylvania are on strike, the company loses nothing.
It may even welcome the strike in order to raise the price of coal on the ground that the supply is short because of your strike.
In that way the company not only breaks your strike, but it also influences public opinion against you, because the people foolishly believe that the higher price of coal is really the result of your strike while in fact it is due to the greed of the mine owners.
You will lose your strike, and for some time to come you and the workers everywhere will have to pay more for coal, and not only for coal but for all the other necessities of life, because together with the price of coal the general cost of living will go up.

Reflect, then, how stupid is the present union policy to permit the other mines to operate while your mine is on strike.
The others remain at work and give financial support to your strike, but don’t you see that their aid only helps to break your strike, because they have to keep on working, really scabbing on you, in order to contribute to your strike fund?
Can anything be more senseless and criminal?

This holds true of every industry and every strike.
Can you wonder that most strikes are lost?
That is the case in America as well as in other countries.
I have before me the Blue Book just published in England under the title of Labor Statistics.
The data prove that strikes do not lead to labor victories.
The figures for the last eight years are as follows:

Results in Favor of:

Year--Working People---Employers
1920---390---507
1921 --152 --315
1922 ---111--- 222
1923 ---187---- 183
1924 ---162 ---235
1925 ---154 ---189
1926 ---67 ---126
1927 ---61 ---118

Actually, then, almost 60% of the strikes were lost.
Incidentally, consider also the loss of working days resulting from strikes, which means no wages.
The total number of workdays lost by English labor in 1912 was 40,890,000, which is almost equal to the lives of 2,000 men, allotting to each 60 years.
In 1919 the number of workdays lost was 34,969,000; in 1920, 26,568,000; in 1921, 85,872,000; in 1926, as a result of the general strike, 162,233,000 days.
These figures do not include time and wages lost through unemployment.

It doesn’t take much arithmetic to see that strikes as at present conducted don’t pay, that the labor unions are not the winners in industrial disputes.

This does not mean, however, that strikes serve no purpose.
On the contrary, they are of great value: they teach the worker the vital need of coöperation, of standing shoulder to shoulder with his fellows and unitedly fighting in the common cause.
Strikes train him in the class struggle and develop his spirit of joint effort, of resistance to the masters, of solidarity and responsibility.
In this sense even an unsuccessful strike is not a complete loss.
Through it the toilers learn that “an injury to one is the concern of all,” the practical wisdom that embodies the deepest meaning of the proletarian struggle.
This does not relate only to the daily battle for material betterment, but equally so to everything pertaining to the worker and his existence, and particularly to matters where justice and liberty are involved.

It is one of the most inspiring things to see the masses roused in behalf of social justice, whomever the case at issue may concern.
For, indeed, it is the concern of all of us, in the truest and deepest sense.
The more labor becomes enlightened and aware of its larger interests, the broader and more universal grow its sympathies, the more world-wide its defense of justice and liberty.
It was a manifestation of this understanding when the workers in every country protested against the judicial murder of Sacco and Vanzetti in Massachusetts.
Instinctively and consciously the masses throughout the world felt, as did all decent men and women, that it is their concern when such a crime is being perpetrated.
Unfortunately that protest, as many similar ones, contented itself with mere resolutions.
Had organized labor resorted to action, such as a general strike, its demands would not have been ignored, and two of the workers’ best friends and noblest of men would not have been sacrificed to the forces of reaction.

Equally important, it would have served as a valuable demonstration of the tremendous power of the proletariat, the power that always conquers when it is unified and resolute.
This has been proven on numerous occasions in the past when the determined stand of labor prevented planned legal outrages, as in the case of Haywood, Moyer, and Pettibone, officials of the Western Federation of Miners, whom the coal barons of the State of Idaho had conspired to send to the gallows during the miners’ strike of 1905.
Again, in 1917, it was the solidarity of the toilers which thwarted the execution of Tom Mooney, in California.
The sympathetic attitude of organized labor in America toward Mexico has also till now been an obstacle to the military occupation of that country by the United States Government in behalf of the American oil interests.
Similarly in Europe united action by the workers has been successful in repeatedly forcing the authorities to grant amnesty to political prisoners.
The Government of England so feared the expressed sympathy of British labor for the Russian Revolution that it was compelled to pretend neutrality.
It did not dare openly to aid the counter-revolution in Russia.
When the dock workers refused to load food and ammunition intended for the White armies, the English Government resorted to deception.
It solemnly assured the workers that the shipments were intended for France.
In the course of my work collecting historic material in Russia, in 1920 and 1921, I came into possession of official British documents proving that the shipments had been immediately forwarded from France, by direct orders of the British Government, to the counter-revolutionary generals in the North of Russia who had established there the so-called Tchaikovsky-Miller Government.
This incident — one out of many — demonstrates the wholesome fear the powers that be have of the awakening class-consciousness and solidarity of the international proletariat.

The stronger the workers grow in this spirit the more effective will be their struggle for emancipation.
Class consciousness and solidarity must assume national and international proportions before labor can attain its full strength.
Wherever there is injustice, wherever persecution and suppression — be it the subjugation of the Philippines, the invasion of Nicaragua, the enslavement of the toilers in the Congo by Belgian exploiters, the oppression of the masses in Egypt, China, Morocco, or India — it is the business of the workers everywhere to raise their voice against all such outrages and demonstrate their solidarity in the common cause of the despoiled and disinherited throughout the world.

Labor is slowly advancing to this social consciousness: strikes and other sympathetic expressions are a valuable manifestation of this spirit.
If the greater number of strikes are lost at present, it is because the proletariat is not yet fully aware of its national and international interests, is not organized on the right principles, and does not sufficiently realize the need of world-wide coöperation.

Your daily struggles for better conditions would quickly assume a different character if you were organized in such a manner that when your factory or mine goes on strike, the whole industry should quit work; not gradually but at once, all at the same time.
Then the employer would be at your mercy, for what could he do when not a wheel turns in the whole industry?
He can get enough strikebreakers for one or a few mills, but an entire industry cannot be supplied with them, nor would he consider it safe or advisable.
Moreover, suspension of work in any one industry would immediately affect a large number of others, because modern industry is interwoven.
The situation would become the direct concern of the whole country, the public would be aroused and demand a settlement.
(At present, when your single factory strikes, no one cares and you may starve as long as you remain quiet.)
That settlement would again depend on yourself, on the strength of your organization.
When the bosses would see that you know your power and that you are determined, they’d give in quickly enough or seek a compromise.
They would be losing millions every day, the strikers might even sabotage the works and machinery, and the employers would be only too anxious to “settle,” while in a strike of one factory or district they usually welcome the situation, knowing as they do that the chances are all against you.

Reflect therefore how important it is in what manner, on what principles your union is built, and how vital labor solitarily and coöperation are in your every-day struggle for better conditions.
In unity is your strength, but that unity is non-existent and impossible as long as you are organized on craft lines instead of by industries.

There is nothing more important and urgent than that you and your fellow workers see to it immediately that you change the form of your organization.

But it is not only the form that must be changed.
Your union must become clear about its aims and purposes.
The worker should most earnestly consider what he really wants, how he means to achieve it, by what methods.
He must learn what his union should be, how it should function, and what it should try to accomplish.

Now, what is the union to accomplish?
What should be the arms of a real labor union?

First of all, the purpose of the union is to serve the interests of its members.
That is its primary duty.
There is no quarrel about that; every workingman understands it.
If some refuse to join a labor body it is because they are too ignorant to appreciate its great value, in which case they must be enlightened.
But generally they decline to belong to the union because they have no faith or are disappointed in it.
Most of those who remain away from the union do so because they hear much boasting about the strength of organized labor while they know, often from bitter experience, that it is defeated in almost every important struggle.
“Oh, the union,” they say scornfully, “it don’t amount to anything.”
To speak quite truthfully, to a certain extent they are right.
They see organized capital proclaim the open shop policy and defeat the unions; they see labor leaders sell out strikes and betray the workers; they see the membership, the rank and file, helpless in the political machinations in and out of the union.
To be sure, they don’t understand why it is so; but they do see the facts, and they turn against the union.

Some again refuse to have anything to do with the union because they had at one time belonged to it, and they know what an insignificant rôle the individual member, the average worker, plays in the affairs of the organization.
The local leaders, the district and central bodies, the national and international officers, and the chiefs of the American Federation of Labor, in the United States, “run the whole show,” they will tell you; “you have nothing to do but vote, and if you object you’ll fly out.”

Unfortunately they are right. You know how the union is managed.
The rank and file have little to say.
They have delegated the whole power to the leaders, and these have become the bosses, just as in the larger life of society the people are made to submit to the orders of those who were originally meant to serve them — the government and its agents. Once you do that, the power you have delegated will be used against you and your own interests every time.
And then you complain that your leaders “misuse their power.”
No, my friend, they don’t misuse it; they only use it, for it is the use of power which is itself the worst misuse.

All this has to be changed if you really want to achieve results.
In society it has to be changed by taking political power away from your governors, abolishing it altogether.
I have shown that political power means authority, oppression, and tyranny, and that it is not political government that we need but rational management of our collective affairs.

Just so in your union you need sensible administration of your business.
We know what tremendous power labor has as the creator of all wealth and the supporter of the world.
If properly organized and united, the workers could control the situation, be the masters of it.
But the strength of the worker is not in the union meeting-hall; it is in the shop and factory, in the mill and mine.
It is there that he must organize; there, on the job.
There he knows what he wants, what his needs are, and it is there that he must concentrate his efforts and his will.
Every shop and factory should have its special committee to attend to the wants and requirements of the men, not leaders, but members of the rank and file, from the bench and furnace, to look after the demands and complaints of their fellow employees.
Such a committee, being on the spot and constantly under the direction and supervision of the workers, wields no power: it merely carries out instructions.
Its members are recalled at will and others selected in their place, according to the need of the moment and the ability required for the task in hand.
It is the workers who decide the matters at issue and carry their decisions out through the shop committees.

That is the character and form of organization that labor needs.
Only this form can express its real purpose and will, be its adequate spokesman, and serve its true interests.

These shop and factory committees, combined with similar bodies in other mills and mines, associated locally, regionally, and nationally, would constitute a new type of labor organization which would be the virile voice of toil and its effective agency.
It would have the whole weight and energy of the united workers back of it and would represent a power tremendous in its scope and potentialities.

In the daily struggle of the proletariat such an organization would be able to achieve victories about which the conservative union, as at present built, cannot even dream.
It would enjoy the respect and confidence of the masses, would attract the unorganized and unite the labor forces on the basis of the equality of all workers and their joint interests and aims.
It would face the masters with the whole might of the working class back of it, in a new attitude of consciousness and strength.
Only then would labor acquire unity and the expression of it assume real significance.

Such a union would soon become something more than a mere defender and protector of the worker.
It would gain a vital realization of the meaning of unity and consequent power, of labor solidarity.
The factory and shop would serve as a training camp to develop the worker’s understanding of his proper rôle in life, to cultivate his self-reliance and independence, teach him mutual help and coöperation, and make him conscious of his responsibility.
He will learn to decide and act on his own judgment, not leaving it to leaders or politicians to attend to his affairs and look out for his welfare.
It will be he who will determine, together with his fellows at the bench, what they want and what methods will best serve their aims, and his committee on the spot would merely carry out instructions.
The shop and factory would become the worker’s school and college.
There he will learn his place in society, his function in industry, and his purpose in life.
He will mature as a workingman and as a man, and the giant of labor will attain his full stature. He will know and be strong thereby.

Not long will he then be satisfied to remain a wage slave, an employee and dependent on the good will of his master whom his toil supports.
He will grow to understand that present economic and social arrangements are wrong and criminal, and he will determine to change them.
The shop committee and union will become the field of preparation for a new economic system, for a new social life.

You see, then, how necessary it is that you and I, and every man and woman who has the interests of labor at heart, work toward these objects.

And right here I want to emphasize that it is particularly urgent that the more advanced proletarian, the radical and the revolutionary, reflect upon this more earnestly, for to most of them, even to some Anarchists, this is only a pious wish, a distant hope.
They fail to realize the transcending importance of efforts in that direction.
Yet it is no mere dream.
Large numbers of progressive workingmen are coming to this understanding: the Industrial Workers of the World and the revolutionary Anarchist-syndicalists in every country are devoting themselves to this end. It is the most pressing need of the present.
It cannot be stressed too much that only the right organization of the workers can accomplish what we are striving for.
In it lies the salvation of labor and of the future.
Organization from the bottom up, beginning with the shop and factory, on the foundation of the joint interests of the workers everywhere, irrespective of trade, race, or country, by means of mutual effort and united will, alone can solve the labor question and serve the true emancipation of man.

“You were speaking of the workers taking over the industries,’ your friend reminds me.
“How are they going to do this?”

Yes, I was on the subject when you made that remark about organization.
But it is well that the matter was discussed, because there is nothing more vital in the problems we are examining.

To return to the taking over of the industries.
It means not only taking them over, but the running of them by labor.
As concerns the taking over, you must consider that the workers are actually now in the industries.
The taking over consists in the workers remaining where they are, yet remaining not as employees but as the rightful collective possessors.

Grasp this point, my friend.
The expropriation of the capitalist class during the social revolution — the taking over of the industries — requires tactics directly the reverse of those you now use in a strike.
In the latter you quit work and leave the boss in full possession of the mill, factory, or mine.
It is an idiotic proceeding, of course, for you give the master the entire advantage: he can put scabs in your place, and you remain out in the cold.

In expropriating, on the contrary, you stay on the job and you put the boss out.
He may remain only on equal terms with the rest: a worker among workers.

The labor organizations of a given place take charge of the public utilities, of the means of communication, of production and distribution in their particular locality.
That is, the telegraphers, the telephone and electrical workers, the railroad men, and so on, take possession (by means of their revolutionary shop committees) of the workshop, factory, or other establishment.
The capitalistic foremen, overseers, and managers are removed from the premises if they resist the change and refuse to coöperate.
If willing to participate, they are made to understand that henceforth there are neither masters nor owners: that the factory becomes public property in charge of the union of workers engaged in the industry, all equal partners in the general undertaking.

It is to be expected that the higher officials of large industrial and manufacturing concerns will refuse to coöperate.
Thus they eliminate themselves.
Their place must be taken by workers previously prepared for the job.
That is why I have emphasized the utmost importance of industrial preparation.
This is a primal necessity in a situation that will inevitably develop and on it will depend, more than on any other factor, the success of the social revolution.
Industrial preparation is the most essential point, for without it the revolution is doomed to collapse.

The engineers and other technical specialists are more likely to join hands with labor when the social revolution comes, particularly if a closer bond and better understanding have in the meantime been established between the manual and mental workers.

Should they refuse and should the workers have failed to prepare themselves industrially and technically, then production would depend on compelling the willfully obstinate to coöperate — an experiment tried in the Russian Revolution and proved a complete failure.

The grave mistake of the Bolsheviki in this connection was their hostile treatment of the whole class of the intelligentsia on account of the opposition of some members of it.
It was the spirit of intolerance, inherent in fanatical dogma, which caused them to persecute an entire social group because of the fault of a few.
This manifested itself in the policy of wholesale vengeance upon the professional elements, the technical specialists, the coöperative organizations, and all cultured persons in general.
Most of them, at first friendly to the Revolution, some even enthusiastic in its favor, were alienated by these Bolshevik tactics, and their coöperation was made impossible.
As a result of their dictatorial attitude the Communists were led to resort to increased oppression and tyranny till they finally introduced purely martial methods in the industrial life of the country.
It was the era of compulsory labor, the militarization of factory and mill, which unavoidably ended in disaster, because forced labor is, by the very nature of coercion, bad and inefficient; moreover, those so compelled react upon the situation by willful sabotage, by systematic delay and spoilage of work, which an intelligent enemy can practice in a way that cannot be detected in due time and which results in greater harm to machinery and product than direct refusal to work.
In spite of the most drastic measures against this kind of sabotage, in spite even of the death penalty, the government was powerless to overcome the evil.
The placing of a Bolshevik, of a political commissar, over every technician in the more responsible positions did not help matters.
It merely created a legion of parasitic officials who, ignorant of industrial matters, only interfered with the work of those friendly to the Revolution and willing to aid, while their unfamiliarity with the task in no way prevented continued sabotage.
The system of forced labor finally developed in what practically became economic counter-revolution, and no efforts of the dictatorship could alter the situation.
It was this that caused the Bolsheviki to change from compulsory labor to a policy of winning over the specialists and technicians by returning them to authority in the industries and rewarding them with high pay and special emoluments.

It would be stupid and criminal to try again the methods which have so signally failed in the Russian Revolution and which, by their very character, are bound to fail every time, both industrially and morally.

The only solution of this problem is the already suggested preparation and training of the workers in the art of organizing and managing industry, as well as closer contact between the manual and technical men.
Every factory, mine, and mill should have its special workers’ council, separate from and independent of the shop committee, for the purpose of familiarizing the workers with the various phases of their particular industry, including the sources of raw material, the consecutive processes of manufacture, by-products, and manner of distribution.
This industrial council should be permanent, but its membership must rotate in such a manner as to take in practically all the employees of a given factory or mill.
To illustrate: suppose the industrial council in a certain establishment consists of five members or of twenty-five, as the case may be, according to the complexity of the industry and the size of the particular factory.
The members of the council, after having thoroughly acquainted themselves with their industry, publish what they had learned for the information of their fellow-workers, and new council members are chosen to continue the industrial studies.
In this manner the whole factory or mill can consecutively acquire the necessary knowledge about the organization and management of their trade and keep step with its development.
These councils would serve as industrial colleges where the workers would become familiar with the technique of their industry in all its phases.

At the same time the larger organization, the union, must use every effort to compel capital to permit greater labor participation in the actual management.
But this, even at best, can benefit only a small minority of the workers.
The plan suggested above, on the other hand, opens the possibility of industrial training to practically every worker in shop, mill, and factory.

It is true, of course, that there are certain kinds of work — such as engineering: civil, electrical, mechanical — which the industrial councils will not be able to acquire by actual practice.
But what they will learn of the general processes of industry will be of inestimable value as preparation. For the rest, the closer bond of friendship and coöperation between worker and technician is a paramount necessity.

The taking over of the industries is therefore the first great object of the social revolution.
It is to be accomplished by the proletariat, by the part of it organized and prepared for the task.
Considerable numbers of workers are already beginning to realize the importance of this and to understand the task before them.
But understanding what is necessary to be done is not sufficient.
Learning how to do it is the next step.
It is up to the organized working class to enter at once upon this preparatory work.

Don't miss the next exciting chapter!!

image.png

Sort:  

Если вам интересно основные проблемы даного текста. Они в романтической позиции анархистов. Вот взять строчку о губернаторах. Когда их просто лишают власти и делают гражданами. Одновременно забывают. Губернатор человек. При своей должности и власти совершал преступления. Например, по ограблению народа. Присвоение добавочной стоимости. Его как любого преступника нельзя сделать просто гражданином. Придется судить и наказать.
Или обобществление средств производства. Анархист Махно от такой практики отказался. Средства производства должны принадлежать людям которые на них работают. Для примера. Я имею землю на этой земле выращиваю овощи и некоторые фрукты. Происходит революция. Зачем у меня забирать землю которую я обрабатываю не привлекая наемного труда? Я землю обрабатываю своими руками. Хотя и с привлечением техники. Меня можно даже расстрелять. Только никто другой не будет обрабатывать землю. Не соберет урожая и как итог не накормит людей. Одновременно я не токарь. Даже если мне подарить токарный станок. Самый современный с ЧПУ. Что я с ним буду делать? Просто не обучен выпускать например шурупы. Хотя имею хобби для переделки мебели и использую шурупы. Логичнее передать средства производства людям, которые на них работают. Умеют ими управлять. Приносят пользу обществу.
Результат? Токарь выпускает шурупы. Я выпускаю картофель. Я даю картофель токарю, другой дает сахар и т.д. Токарь дает нам шурупы. В итоге токарь и его семья сыты. Я имею нужные мне предметы для жизни и хобби.

Да, эта книга описывает, как это сделать.
Когда я делаю серию, ее можно скопировать и вставить в переводчик, если вы не можете найти где-нибудь pdf на русском языке.

Оттуда мы попадаем, продолжая делать ту работу, которая нам подходит, отказываясь при этом платить валюту за любой продукт.
Пусть бухгалтеры балансируют на математике, пока работники продолжают заполнять полки, полки будут заполнены, платим ли мы за товары в декретной валюте или просто в кредит магазина.

Каждый, кто работает, получает по одной доле от всех продуктов труда, те, кто не работает, все равно получают основы, пока имеют дело с тем, что мешает им что-либо производить.

Теперь мы носим с собой всех бездельников, за исключением того, что сейчас мы платим десяткам бюрократов за ведение бухгалтерского учета.
Мы добиваемся эффективности, давая бездельникам то, что им нужно в магазинах, и заставляя бюрократов работать продуктивно.

Переведено с помощью www.DeepL.com/Translator (бесплатная версия)

I agree with you in many ways. However, the position of the Bolsheviks is closer to me. For example, money. In the USSR, there were banknotes, not money. Although I suspect the translator will translate incorrectly.
There were symbols of money. It could be anything. Coins, banknotes, coupons plastic card with symbols.An example of the use of plastic cards by large corporations. The employee is given a card. It allows you to pass through different doors, depending on your status in the company. He comes to the dining room. Orders lunch. He doesn't pay for lunch. Swipes the map. There is a deduction of points. He gets his lunch of his choice. Conditionally: chicken noodles, potatoes, cutlet, salad and a glass of juice. 10 points were deducted. I took milk soup, rice, meatballs, another salad, another juice. Deduction of 12 points. The employee knows the number of points on the plastic card per month. To calculate their spending.
It's not money. He doesn't work for food. Receives a salary on a bank card. Plastic work card other.

I am sure that such cards are used not only in Russia. I'm sure you have an analog. And with this card, I can get food only in the canteen of my corporation. In all other cases, it's just a useless piece of plastic.

As a result, the exchange of goods and services through money symbols is convenient. In the modern world? It may even be a kind of "cryptocurrency".

Now about statistics and accounting. They are extremely useful under socialism, and even more so under communism. To know how many pants to sew. How many cups, cups, plates for cats, leashes for dogs, and so on.
Slackers? They will not exist under communism, they will disappear even under socialism. How was it in the USSR? There was a society of relatively equal people.
How do you make a friend? How to get a romantic relationship? If money doesn't decide...
you have to be an interesting person. Engage in some respectable business. Otherwise, you just have money and you're a dummy. You're not interested in being a friend. You won't have a family.

By the book. I use Yandex Browser. It automatically translates any text. When in the form of images, you need to upload the image. Then he writes on the photo written and translated.
Regarding books. I don't mind reading and developing at all. Only in the last few days you have offered to read about 6 books. I read fast. That's just not fast enough to overcome 6 books for 3 days :-))))
If you're not too upset, I have a suggestion. Let's analyze 1 book each and talk about it in detail. Then we can move on to Book 2, etc.

Да, конечно, не торопитесь, мне понадобилось много лет, чтобы прочитать мой список для чтения.

I also read books. Therefore, I am closer to the position of Stalin. The collection of Lenin's works is extremely interesting. For example, the economic decisions of Stalin. Building an industry of group A. When you first need to establish the production of means of production. Then comes Group B.
Bottom line we have a common goal and disputes to achieve the goals.

If you are interested in the main problems of this text. They are in the romantic position of anarchists. That is to take place on governors. When they are simply deprived of power and made citizens. They forget at the same time. The governor is a man. In his position and power, he committed crimes. For example, for robbing people. Assignment of added value. He, like any criminal, cannot be made a mere citizen. You will have to judge and punish.
Or the socialization of the means of production. The anarchist Makhno abandoned this practice. The means of production must belong to the people who work for them. For example. I have land on this land I grow vegetables and some fruits. A revolution is taking place. Why take away from me the land that I cultivate without attracting hired labor? I work the land with my own hands. Although with the involvement of technology. You can even shoot me. Only no one else will work the land. It will not harvest and as a result will not feed people. At the same time, I'm not a turner. Even if you give me a lathe. The most modern CNC machine. What am I going to do with it? Just not trained to produce such screws. Although I have a hobby for remodeling furniture and use screws. It is more logical to transfer the means of production to the people who work for them. They know how to manage them. They benefit society.
The result? The turner produces screws. I'm releasing potatoes. I give potatoes to the turner, another gives sugar, etc. The turner gives us the screws. As a result, the turner and his family are full. I have the items I need for my life and hobbies.

Да, это возможно, мы просто должны отказаться от валюты банкиров и работать с собственной валютой, если мы хотим сохранить капитализм, или мы бросаем большинство бухгалтеров и всех юристов и политиков в торговые школы, чтобы они тоже могли стать продуктивными.
И тогда мы просто позволяем людям потреблять то, что им нужно, чтобы быть счастливыми в обмен на несколько продуктивных часов работы.
Кропоткин говорит, что для поддержания уровня жизни каждого достаточно ~20 000 часов, я бы сейчас предположил, что благодаря автоматизации это будет меньше.
Дело не в том, что больше работы не найти, а в том, что новая шкала оплаты включает в себя досуг, который раньше приносился в жертву за более новую машину или более красивую квартиру.

Мы можем управлять этим миром лучше, чем то, что сейчас на нас давит.

Переведено с помощью www.DeepL.com/Translator (бесплатная версия)

Banks should be banned. There should only be a state-owned bank. You probably haven't heard the theory about negative loans. Let's say you need $ 100 for personal needs. Take this consumer loan. They are obliged to return $ 80 or $ 60 to the state bank, depending on their work experience.
In other words, not one private bank can do this. In the USSR, there was such a practice. It raised the standard of living of ordinary citizens. As a result, there was also an economic benefit.

Now with regard to leisure. Kropotkin was still a theorist. In the USSR, there was a practice. Usually speaking about leisure, everyone mentions 2 professions of a musician and an artist.
More often, a hobby that is chosen by people who are much more mundane.

For example, I like to grow fruits and vegetables. I have a hobby of making furniture. When you pick up a spoiled unnecessary thing. Then you finish the work and it's better than a new thing, beautiful. You feel like a creator. Or here is growing vegetables. When a small sprout breaks through the soil. You water it. Then you collect the results of your work.

In addition, we have hobbies in the form of fishing, collecting mushrooms. In other words, if a person has free time. He won't just lie there and spit at the ceiling. He'll do something interesting. This case will benefit the society.

Will there be those who don't want to do anything? Of course! That's just the USSR showed. Such people will not be respected. They won't find friends. They won't start a family. Motivation by public approval. Or the motivation of public censure. This, believe me, is not always weaker than the motivation to make money.
The result is a strange thing. Conditionally -20,000 hours of mandatory work.
And maybe 200,000 hours of doing what you love. Hobbies can also be useful.
It is even found in some of the poems of the time. The translator will not be able to translate the verses. So I'll just pass on their contents.
I wish winter would come sooner. The reservoir will be covered with ice. I'll do some ice fishing. I'll give the fish to my friends and neighbors. I don't need it. I just like fishing.
In other words, a person wants to do a favorite hobby. The result of the work of his hobby is not very important to him. The process is important to him. He has no problems with money. Therefore, the question of food is not worth it. At the same time, it benefits society by distributing the catch (fish) to friends and neighbors.
Give me more time. Give free accessories and many materials. Why would I sell the restored furniture? Moreover, I do not need so much furniture in my house and my city apartment. Therefore, under such conditions, I will simply start distributing it to friends and neighbors. I'll be morally pleased to know. The satisfaction that they use beautiful and high-quality things and know that I created them with my own hands.
The creator's pride in his work. The result? 20 hours a week of mandatory work. And everything else is a hobby. That's just leisure will also benefit society.

Да, это именно то, что предсказывает Bellamy.

What do you think about the practice of negative loans in the USSR? The meaning of the loan? You take 100 coins, give back 60-80 coins? Or do you think it is necessary to initially abandon any currency? Do not have a transition period.